Data Set Description for Chapter 2: Cyclical Majorities

Data Exercise Contributor: Jens Wäckerle

Dataset-Chapter-2.utf8

In this online exercise, we will take a more detailed look at cyclical majorities that are discussed in chapter 2. Differently from the exercises for the other chapters in the book, we will not introduce a dataset here, as chapter 2 focuses on the theoretical model used throughout the book. Nevertheless, we can still think of tasks and questions that you should attempt to answer as you work through the theoretical exercise we present here.

Table 1: General Tasks and Questions
Tasks
When can we consider politics to be unidimensional vs multidimensional?
Under what conditions within a political system is it easier to change policy? When is it harder?
How can we avoid the problem of cyclical majorities and achieve stable policy within a political system?

Starting Point

As we learned in chapter 2, political positions can be depicted in a one- or multidimensional model. Although, or rather because, these models simplify reality, they provide us with a valuable tool to understand political decisions. Figure 1 shows such an arrangement of political positions on two dimensions, the level of public spending on a park and the level of access to it. In this example, we have five actors, A, B, C, D, and E. All of these actors have one distinct position in the two-dimensional model. For example, actor A wants a high level of spending and open access to non-taxpayers. In the following, we assume that the voters will have to make a decision about how to run the park. Thus, we need to understand which compromises have a majority among the five citizens.

Figure 1: Preferences of Actors in a Two-Dimensional Space

Figure 1: Preferences of Actors in a Two-Dimensional Space

Indifference Curves

Which points do the five voters prefer over a status quo policy that is currently in place? We can easily model this spatially. Figure 2 shows an example for two of the actors (actor B and D) and a hypothetical status quo SQ (with moderate spending for the park and limited access to non-taxpayers). Because an actor always prefers policies closer to their ideal point, actor B should prefer any policy that is closer. This is shown using an indifference curve, the circle that is centered at B’s ideal point with a radius equal to the distance between B and the status quo. The actor B is indifferent to the SQ for all points that lie on the circle (because there are equally good policies). Anything inside the circle is preferred by B, shown by the colored area. Similarly, D prefers all points inside the circle around her position. Note that there is some overlap in the circles. Both B and D would prefer policies in this overlapping area, the so called winset of the status quo, and could agree on a policy proposed within this winset if they were the only actors.

Figure 2: Indifference Curves

Figure 2: Indifference Curves

A First Proposal

Imagine the five voters come together in a town hall meeting. The mayor is part of this group and holds preferences at point D. Assume for now that this town hall meeting is an open forum in which all policy proposals can be voted against each other alternative. That is, no one has gatekeeping or agenda-setting powers, but simply the alternative supported by a majority should prevail.

Suppose now that mayor D speaks first at the meeting and introduces his plan, located at his own position, D. Following this presentation, citizen E comes forward and proposes a new proposal P1. This new proposal is now voted against proposal D. It turns out that P1 is preferred by a coalition of A, B, and E. This is shown in Figure 3, which depicts the areas in the policy space that each citizen prefers over proposal D. Remember that the indifference curves show at which point the actors are indifferent between policy position D and a policy alternative (because it is equidistant from the actors’ respective ideal points). An actor prefers any outcome within her circle (indifference curve) to the status quo. She is indifferent between the status quo and any point along the curve, and she prefers the status quo over any point outside of her indifference curve.

Figure 3: Voting on P1 Versus Proposal D

Figure 3: Voting on P1 Versus Proposal D

Counterproposals

P1 has now obtained a majority, but the discussion is not over. Citizen A is not happy with the outcome; she wants a better park, i.e. higher level of spending, but roughly the same level of access. She proposes policy P2, which is voted against P1 (Figure 4). This proposal also obtains a majority, with A, B, and C voting for it. Actors D and E would be worse off under this alternative and oppose the measure.